#booksummaries #binomialmodelinfinance #llms
> Continuing from [Binomial Models in Finance, Part 1](Binomial%20Models%20in%20Finance,%20Part%201.md) last week, here is how [Claude 3 Opus 200k](https://poe.com/Claude-3-Opus-200k) summarized chapter 2 of the book. Again I did ask follow up questions and then malingered the pieces together.
Sure, here's a summary of the key points from Chapter 2 of Binomial Models in Finance:
The Basic Model
The chapter introduces the one-step binomial model, which has two times (t=0 and t=1) and two assets:
1. A risky asset S with known value S(0) at t=0, and two possible values S(1,↑) and S(1,↓) at t=1.
2. A riskless asset B with value B(0)=1 at t=0 and B(1,↑) = B(1,↓) = R at t=1. Usually R ≥ 1, representing the risk-free return.
To avoid arbitrage, the model assumes S(1,↓) < RS(0) < S(1,↑).
Pricing Contingent Claims
Given a claim X that pays X(1,↑) and X(1,↓) at t=1, its price X(0) at t=0 is found in two steps:
Step 1: Find H0 and H1 such that X(1) = H0B(1) + H1S(1). This is the replicating portfolio.
Step 2: By the Law of One Price, X(0) = H0 + H1S(0).
This leads to the general pricing formula:
X(0) = [πX(1,↑) + (1-π)X(1,↓)] / R
where π = [RS(0) - S(1,↓)] / [S(1,↑) - S(1,↓)] is the risk-neutral probability.
Types of Arbitrage
The chapter discusses two types of arbitrage:
1. Type 1: Making a profit at t=0 without any liabilities at t=1.
2. Type 2: Starting with nothing at t=0, having no liabilities at t=1, but making a profit in some state at t=1.
The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein (CRR) Model
In the CRR model, S(1,↑) = uS(0) and S(1,↓) = dS(0), with 0 < d < R < u. The risk-neutral probability is π = (R-d)/(u-d), and the pricing formula becomes:
X(0) = [πX(1,↑) + (1-π)X(1,↓)] / R
The CRR formula for a European call option with strike K is:
C(0) = [π(uS(0)-K)+ + (1-π)(dS(0)-K)+] / R
Call-Put Parity Formula
For European call (C) and put (P) options with the same strike K and expiry T,
C(0) - P(0) = S(0) - K/R
This is proved both in the CRR model and in a model-independent way using arbitrage arguments.
Non-Arbitrage Inequalities
Several model-independent inequalities are derived using arbitrage arguments, including:
- Lower bounds for European calls: C(t) ≥ max(S(t) - PV(K), 0)
- For American call options on non-dividend paying stocks: CA(t) > (S(t) - K)+
- Calls are decreasing in time to maturity: Cτ1(t) ≥ Cτ2(t) if τ1 > τ2
Key takeaways:
1) The one-step binomial model and CRR model provide a framework for pricing contingent claims.
2) Risk-neutral probabilities are derived from the no-arbitrage principle.
3) Call-put parity and other inequalities are proved using arbitrage arguments.
4) The chapter lays the foundation for the binomial option pricing approach.
> Some follow up questions I asked to clarify some terminology and syntax.
> "Please explain this European and American call thing"
Sure, let's dive into the differences between European and American call options.
European Call Options:
- A European call option gives the holder the right, but not the obligation, to buy the underlying asset at a predetermined price (the strike price) on a specific future date (the expiration date).
- The key feature is that a European call can only be exercised at expiration. This means even if the option is "in-the-money" (i.e., the stock price is above the strike price) before expiration, the holder cannot exercise the option early.
- The payoff at expiration is max(S(T)-K, 0), where S(T) is the stock price at expiration and K is the strike price.
- In the CRR model, the price of a European call at time 0 is given by:
C(0) = [π(uS(0)-K)+ + (1-π)(dS(0)-K)+] / R
where u, d are the up and down factors for the stock price, R is the risk-free return, and π is the risk-neutral probability.
American Call Options:
- An American call option also gives the holder the right to buy the underlying asset at the strike price, but the key difference is that an American call can be exercised at any time up to and including the expiration date.
- This early exercise feature provides an additional benefit to the holder compared to a European call.
- However, for a non-dividend paying stock, it is never optimal to exercise an American call early. This is because the time value of money makes it more profitable to sell the option instead of exercising it.
- In this case, the American call price will be the same as the European call price.
- But if the stock pays dividends, it can be optimal to exercise an American call just before an ex-dividend date. This is to capture the dividend which the option holder is not entitled to.
Non-Arbitrage Inequalities:
The chapter derives some important inequalities for European and American call prices:
1. For a European call, C(t) ≥ max(S(t) - PV(K), 0). This lower bound comes from the fact that a call option is always worth at least its intrinsic value.
2. For an American call on a non-dividend paying stock, CA(t) > (S(t) - K)+ for t < T. This means the American call price is always strictly greater than its exercise value before expiration. Exercising early is not optimal because the time value of money makes the unexercised option more valuable.
3. American calls are always at least as valuable as European calls: CA(t) ≥ CE(t). This is because American calls offer all the rights of European calls plus the additional right of early exercise.
4. Call options are decreasing in time to maturity: If τ1 > τ2, then Cτ1(t) ≥ Cτ2(t). A call with a longer time to expiration is always at least as valuable as a call with a shorter time to expiration, all else being equal.
These inequalities provide important bounds and relationships for call option prices. They are derived using arbitrage arguments, i.e., by showing that if these relations are violated, it would create an opportunity for riskless profit.
In summary, while European and American calls both give the right to buy the underlying asset, the key difference is the timing of when that right can be exercised. This difference, along with the stock's dividend policy, leads to different optimal exercise strategies and price relationships for the two types of options.
> Please explain this notation "A risky asset S with known value S(0) at t=0, and two possible values S(1,↑) and S(1,↓) at t=1." Specifically the S(1,↑) and S(1,↓).
Certainly! The notation S(1,↑) and S(1,↓) is used to represent the two possible values that the risky asset S can take at time t=1 in the one-step binomial model.
In this model, there are only two time points: t=0 (the present) and t=1 (a future point in time). At t=0, the value of the asset S is known with certainty and is denoted by S(0).
However, at t=1, there is uncertainty about the value of S. The model assumes that there are only two possible states of the world at t=1, which are referred to as the "up" state and the "down" state.
- In the "up" state, denoted by ↑, the asset's value is S(1,↑). This represents a favorable scenario where the asset's price has gone up.
- In the "down" state, denoted by ↓, the asset's value is S(1,↓). This represents an unfavorable scenario where the asset's price has gone down.
The specific values of S(1,↑) and S(1,↓) are inputs to the model and are typically chosen to represent a realistic range of possible future outcomes for the asset price.
In the Cox-Ross-Rubinstein (CRR) model, a specific form is assumed for these values:
- S(1,↑) = uS(0)
- S(1,↓) = dS(0)
Here, u and d are constants with u > 1 and 0 < d < 1. They represent the proportional increase (u) or decrease (d) in the asset price over the time period from t=0 to t=1.
The key feature of the binomial model is that it simplifies the continuous range of possible future prices into just two discrete outcomes. This simplification allows for tractable computation of option prices and hedging strategies, while still capturing the essential feature of asset price uncertainty.
The notation S(1,↑) and S(1,↓) is a concise way to represent these two possible future states in the mathematical formulation of the model. It's a foundational part of the setup of the one-step binomial model, which is then extended to multi-period binomial models in later chapters of the book.